Handbook of Income Distribution

Martin Ravallion , in Handbook of Income Distribution, 2015

22.3 The Utility of Poverty

For much of the sixteenth through eighteenth centuries, when Western Europe was mired in poverty, the dominant economic theory of the time, mercantilism, saw poverty as a natural country of affairs and, indeed, instrumentally good, as a means of encouraging work effort. The mercantilist goal was to maximize a nation'southward export surplus—the remainder of trade, which was equated with the future prosperity and power of the realm—and the means were inexpensive production inputs, that is, cheap raw materials (for which colonies proved useful) and cheap, and therefore poor, labor at home. Poverty was non just accepted; it was seen as an essential precondition for a country's economic development. Hunger would encourage piece of work, and lack of it would practise the opposite. The seemingly widely held economic premise was that the individual supply curve for unskilled work was negatively sloped—in modernistic economic terms, that the income effect on demand for leisure dominated the exchange consequence. As the Reverend Townsend (1786) put it: "The poor know lilliputian of the motives which stimulate the higher ranks to activity—pride, honor and ambition. In general, it is only hunger which can spur and catalyst them onto labor" (p. 23). And so: "… in proportion as you advance the wages of the poor, you diminish the quantity of their piece of work" (p. 29). 12

The idea of a negatively sloped labor supply curve is essentially what Furniss (1920, p. 117) later dubbed "the utility of poverty." The footing for this idea appears to take been little more than coincidental anecdotes; Furniss (1920, Chapter vi) provides many examples from writings of the time, often with references to the attractions of the alehouse when workers got a wage increase. It was not the concluding time in the history of thought about poverty that coincidental incentive arguments resting on little or no good evidence would buttress strong policy positions.

A continuing future supply of inexpensive labor was also seen to be crucial. Large families were encouraged and good work habits were to be instilled from an early age. Like higher current wages, too much schooling would discourage both current and future work effort. Consistent with this model, few sustainable opportunities were expected to be available to whatsoever educated children from poor families. In de Mandeville'southward (1732, pp. 288–311) heed, the just realistic future prospect for the children of laboring (and hence poor) parents was to be laboring and poor. Poor parents had little realistic hope that their children would be anything but poor; their low aspirations simply reflected and rationalized their lack of opportunity. Pocket-sized amounts of schooling would have served little purpose. In this view of economical evolution, in that location was little or no prospect of reducing wealth poverty—including escaping the poverty trap demonstrated in Effigy 22.i. In that location was trivial or no perceived scope for up mobility of working class children. They were born poor and stayed poor.

Modern progressive thinkers may be shocked by de Mandeville's views (and similar views still heard occasionally in modern times), simply there may well exist an element of savage truth to them. His claim that a modest amount of extra schooling for working form children is wasted is consistent with the model in Figure 22.one. Suppose that the poor—the working class—are concentrated at the wealth poverty trap (point A in Effigy 22.i). A pocket-size increase in their wealth, in the class of extra man capital just sufficient to get them to the threshold (say), will not bring whatsoever lasting benefit. In due course, the dynamics will push them back to signal A. A big gain in schooling is needed.

And de Mandeville's pessimism about schooling would not surprise many poor children in the developing world today. Katherine Boo's (2012) vivid description of life in a Mumbai slum includes a discussion of the choices made past Sunil, a young scavenger who spends long hours collecting whatsoever he can observe of whatever value in the trash deposits around Mumbai airport. Sunil is clearly very poor. He is also clearly capable of learning and is aware that with sufficient schooling he might escape his wretched life. But how can he finance sufficient schooling? At one point, he spends a few days in a private after-hours school run by a college pupil who lives in the slum, and later on much rote learning he masters the "twinkle-star" vocal. xiii Boo (2012, p. 68) writes:

He'd sabbatum in on [the English language class taught in the slum] for a few days, mastering the English twinkle-star song, earlier deciding that his time was better spent working for food.

By estimation, the modest amount of schooling that Sunil could beget would exist insufficient for him to escape poverty. He is ameliorate off addressing his current hunger.

22.3.1 Early on Social Protection Policies

Recall that the poverty trap in Figure 22.1 has people stuck at nada wealth but they still earn enough to survive (as Sunil does through scavenging). Higher wages or prices for their outputs increase their welfare, and uninsured shocks to their health (say) have the reverse effect. There is space hither for social protection policies providing state-contingent income support. Such policies can exist and exist seen every bit reasonably effective without irresolute the fact that poor people are stuck in the wealth poverty trap.

Information technology has long been argued that governments have a role in social protection from shocks that threaten extreme poverty. For example, around 300 BC, the famous Indian academic and advisor to royalty, Chanakya (likewise known every bit Kautilya), recommended that when famine looms a skilful king should "… institute the building of forts or h2o-works with the grant of nutrient, or share [his] provisions [with the people], or entrust the state [to some other king]" (quoted in Drèze, 1990a, p. 75). If i thinks of antipoverty policy primarily in terms of protection from adverse events, then the idea is very onetime indeed.

Even though mainstream economic thinking has for a long time encouraged a limited part for the land in social protection, more contentious has been the thought of promotion. In the premercantilist feudal and slave economies, the employer had a responsibility for insuring workers, even very poor workers, who may well have faced exploitation only were at least protected to some degree. (This was not necessarily donating in any sense; a slave owner had a purely selfish interest in keeping his property alive.) The new elites in the early development of capitalism were keen to see the state take over these roles, but consistently with their economical ideas. The status quo distribution of wealth was seen past its defenders as the issue of natural processes, which included the competitive marketplace mechanism, and information technology was not to be tampered with through policy. Persistent poverty was believed to be the natural guild of things until modern times. By dissimilarity, transient poverty was seen as a threat to the social gild. There was at to the lowest degree an implicit recognition of the limitations of free markets in providing insurance confronting risk.

The sixteenth and seventeenth centuries saw the emergence of fledgling social policies in Europe in response to rising "pauperism." At that place were increasing numbers of confused and unemployed workers and beggars on city streets. Although the cause was widely seen to be the moral weaknesses of poor people, deeper explanations could exist found in changes in the organization of production (including in agriculture with the breakup of feudalism) combined with greater mobility (also with implications for family support of the aged). Although unemployment was non commonly identified equally a cause of poverty, work was widely seen as the solution. Publicly financed workhouses were introduced effectually 1600. Welfare recipients were incarcerated and obliged to work for their upkeep. From the kickoff, the idea was that the workhouses would be "self-targeting," in that but the poorest would exist willing to exist so confined, thus providing a cost-effective ways of poverty relief (Thane, 2000, p. 115). Only the policy was likewise grounded in the prevailing view that poverty was acquired past bad behaviors, which could be controlled and (hopefully) corrected by the workhouses. The workhouses were seen as a cost-effective policy for moral reform.

At that place was a strong element of protection in the workhouse idea; anyone thrown into poverty past some shock could plough to the workhouse. Was information technology too a promotional policy? There is not much word in the literature about the promotional value to poor people of the work done beyond the perceived moral value of actually doing work. Advocates might well debate that this was promotion through behavioral alter. Only information technology was clearly non promotion by relieving the constraints facing poor people.

22.3.2 England's Poor Laws

A major policy response to poverty emerged in Elizabethan England in the form of the Poor Laws. 14 This was a organisation of publicly provided insurance confronting income poverty due to specific sources, notably old age, widowhood, disability, affliction, or unemployment. Essentially the cardinal government instructed local parishes to deal with their poverty problem. Equally a arrangement of protection, the Poor Laws were quite comprehensive and came to be reasonably generous in some places. 15 Arguably the height of the Poor Laws was the Speenhamland Organisation of 1795 introduced by the justices of Berkshire. This system aimed to ensure a guaranteed minimum income through a sliding scale of wage supplements indexed to the price of bread (Himmelfarb, 1984a; Montagu, 1971).

The antipoverty programs elsewhere in Europe around this fourth dimension relied heavily on charitable giving and and so faced gratis-rider problems; levels of church and individual spending on transfers to poor people were low—well under ane% of national income in nearly countries (Lindert, 2013). In contrast, the disbursements under the Poor Laws in England and Wales were largely financed by local property revenue enhancement. There was apparently some displacement of private clemency, though the latter continued to exist (Hindle, 2004; Lindert, 2013). But at that place tin be picayune dubiety that the Poor Laws entailed a internet gain in social protection. By the tardily seventeenth century almost all parishes of England and Wales were covered, and, under the "Old Poor Laws" up to the nineteenth century, all persons were eligible for relief. (New Poor Laws came out of reforms in the 1830s, which I return to later.) The parishes had the responsibleness for implementation, field of study to monitoring past central authorities. Beingness based in the parishes was convenient but possibly never platonic as they provided limited scope for pooling risks, and at that place was undoubtedly considerable horizontal inequity (whereby equally poor people in different parishes fared very differently). 16 Nor could these policies e'er be expected to have much bear on on the steady-state wealth distribution. However, it is clear that the Onetime Poor Laws did provide a degree of protection from risk, and it has been argued that they helped break the historical link between harvest failures and mortality (Kelly and Cormac, 2010; Smith, 2011).

The Poor Laws appear to have helped ensure a relatively docile and sustained working class, with lilliputian threat to the steady-state distribution of wealth. Solar (1995) argues that the Old Poor Laws were crucial to England's long-term social stability, including periods (such equally the belatedly eighteenth century) of concern about the possibility of the dramatic instability in France spilling across the English Aqueduct. Broad political support was ensured by the fact that anyone could get relief if needed. For case, widowhood was a threat to many of those who would not normally expect to turn to the parish for relief. 17 Equally novels of the time often pointed out, even the well-to-do upper eye class family could be vulnerable to poverty (a favorite theme of Charles Dickens).

Fleischacker's (2004, p. 51) give-and-take of England'southward Poor Laws argues that they were motivated by the "… virtue of charity rather than the virtue of justice," and equally such they did non plant the beginnings of the modern role for public policy in assuring distributive justice. 1 can conjecture that the motivation for the Poor Laws was at least equally much to do with maintaining social stability as charity or justice. Still, any may take been the motives of policy makers, the Poor Laws constituted a legally enforceable state policy for limited relief from the specified events, financed by redistributive taxes. And parish residents (though non outsiders) had a legal recourse under the Poor Laws, which is why they could aid ensure social stability over some 300 years (Solar, 1995). Against Fleischacker'due south estimation, information technology seems that the Poor Laws came very close to being a premodern example of policies to help ensure distributive justice.

Notwithstanding, an attribute of the Poor Laws that should not be ignored is that they were clearly intended for protection rather than promotion. These laws were an early on form of social insurance intended for a world in which the poor and the middle form faced many uninsured risks associated with uncertain employment, wellness crises, harvest failures, and elementary bad luck (Hindle, 2004). Such risks may well have spilled over into production, with agin long-term consequences. Past assuring greater social stability, this, too, may take brought long-term gains. Nevertheless, it is articulate that any longer-term promotional advantages were attained via the enhanced protection that was attained under the Poor Laws. Protection was clearly seen as the main aim of the Poor Laws.

Instead of focusing on whether the motivation was charity or justice, the more than important reason why the Elizabethan Poor Laws, or Chanakya's famine relief policy, did not constitute a comprehensive antipoverty policy is that these policies were unlikely to change the steady-land distribution of the levels of wealth. In terms of the model in Section 22.ii, what these policies were doing was preventing the consumption levels of those either stuck in the wealth poverty trap or settled at some low steady-country level of wealth from falling also much. They provided a degree of protection only did little to help people permanently escape poverty. By the economical logic of the mercantilists, hunger was a practiced thing as it motivated poor people to work, with social protection playing a express and well-defined role. Later on all, just similar the slave owner, mercantilists believed that ane must go on the workers live.

By the late eighteenth century, a significant alter in thinking was underway.

Read total chapter

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B9780444594297000236

The Emergence of the Engineering Sciences: An Historical Analysis

David F. Channell , in Philosophy of Engineering science and Engineering Sciences, 2009

3.three The study of machines

During the eighteenth and 19thursday centuries, developments in the report of machines contributed to the emergence of the engineering science sciences. With the new demands for manufacturing brought near by mercantilism and industrialization, scientists and engineers began to focus their attention on agreement and improving machines [ Reynolds, 1983]. Throughout much of the 18th century the report of machines focused on the waterwheel. Building on Galileo's thought that machines should be analyzed in terms of their ability to utilize the forces of nature in the most efficient manner, the Frenchman Antoine Parent used the differential calculus to calculate the maximum efficiency of undershot waterwheels in 1704. A few years later Henri Pitot calculated the optimum number of blades an undershot waterwheel of a given size should take and presented his calculations in tabular form. By mid-century a debate arose whether the undershot or overshot waterwheel was the virtually efficient. Antoine de Parcieux, a member of the French Academy of Sciences, conducted a series of experimental tests using calibration models and concluded that the overshot wheel was more efficient. At about the aforementioned time, John Smeaton in Uk began conducting an all-encompassing serial of experiments in which he systematically varied the type of wheel, the quantity of flowing h2o, the caput of water, and the load on the wheel, and ended that the overshot bike was more efficient. His experiments would aid establish a new "tradition of testability" [Constant, 1980, p. 20]. Smeaton's technique would subsequently be called "parameter variation," and would become an important methodology of the engineering science sciences [Vincenti, 1990, pp. 146–151].

The experimental research on waterwheels encouraged new theoretical piece of work. In France, Jean Charles Borda, a member of the Academy of Sciences, analyzed waterwheels in terms of vis viva (mv2 — which is related to the mod concept of kinetic energy) and concluded that the inefficiencies of the undershot wheel were the result of vis viva being lost to turbulence. In 1783 Lazare Carnot, in his Essai sur les machines en genéral extended Borda's analysis of waterwheels and developed a theory that was applicable to all machines [Gillispie, 1971]. By applying the thought of vis viva to machines Carnot concluded that all impacts and shocks needed to be avoided.

By the 19th century the combination of experimental and theoretical studies of machines led to new blueprint principles. In 1824 Jean Victor Poncelet designed a new waterwheel based on the work of Borda and Carnot. In America during the middle of the nineteenth century James B. Francis began a series of all-encompassing experiments on a water turbine designed by Benoit Fourneyron [Layton, 1979]. Combining both the experiments and theoretical work based on Newtonian mechanics, Francis adult a series of blueprint principles for turbines. At almost the same time, K.G. Coriolis in French republic and William Whewell and Henry Moseley in Britain employed the thought of piece of work to analyze machines. By comparing the transmitted work to the wasted piece of work, they analyzed machines in terms of efficiency which would become another fundamental concept of the engineering science sciences.

Machines like waterwheels and turbines could exist seen every bit devices that transmitted and modified force or piece of work but machines could also be seen as devices that transmitted and modified motion. If 1 neglected the action of dynamic forces, a machine could be analyzed in terms of what became known every bit the theory of mechanisms [Ferguson, 1962; Hartenberg and Denavit, 1964], an idea that went back to Leonardo Da Vinci. By the beginning of the 18thursday century the Swedish natural philosopher Christopher Polhem created a Laboratorium mechanicum by collecting mechanisms from beyond Sweden. He put forward the idea that all machines could be created from a "mechanical alphabet" with the five aboriginal machines serving as vowels and other mechanisms serving every bit consonants. Throughout the eighteenth and 19th centuries several institutions, such equally the Conservatoire des Arts et Métiers in Paris, the Royal Institution in London and the Franklin Institute in Philadelphia, established big collections of mechanisms in gild to provide a basis for the understanding and improvement of machinery. At the end of the 18th century and the beginning of the nineteenth century Gaspard Monge at the École Polytechnique argued that machines could all-time exist understood by analyzing the elements of a motorcar that converted 1 type of movement into another. In gild to do so, Monge and his followers, Agustin de Betancourt, Pierre Hâchette and Phillipe Lanz, developed a organization to classify mechanisms that was similar to Carl Linnaeus', binomial nomenclature system for plants. This work was extended by André-Marie Ampère, who coined the term cmématique, later called kinematics.

Past the middle of the 19th century Robert Willis at Cambridge began studying mechanisms in terms of the relationship of motions created past the machinery, seeing that the action of a mechanism was contained of the given motion that was applied to the machinery. Past the 2d half of the century, Franz Reuleaux, at Charlottenberg, further extended the theory of mechanisms by moving away from the study of private mechanisms and toward the analysis of mechanisms every bit part of an integrated organization. Particularly important work was also done past James Clerk Maxwell in Britain in 1868 with his assay of mechanical governors which led to one of the earliest theories of feedback command [Mayr, 1970].

Read full affiliate

URL:

https://world wide web.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B9780444516671500094

Economic science

Leonardo Becchetti , ... Stefano Zamagni , in The Microeconomics of Wellbeing and Sustainability, 2020

one.14 Colonial expansion and mercantilism

In the historical menstruation between the stop of the 1500s and the beginning of the 1700s the first big modern states were formed. The consolidation of the cracking European powers (England, Espana, France, and the Netherlands) was accompanied by a series of economical interventions to back up their commercial activities. All these contributions together were chosen "mercantilism."

This phenomenon, which was comprised of more than one schoolhouse of thought, represented a ready of techniques and rules of conduct for merchants and ministers of the economy.

Mercantilism is a set of rules, practical directions, and economic policy suggestions addressed to sovereigns to increase a country's wealth. Mercantilism held that the wealth of a nation was measured by the quantity of gilded and precious metals it possessed; that is why mercantilists supported the reasoning of colonial policy and protectionism. Traditional societies were transformed from transient associations between individuals for the purpose of single business deals into permanent organizations to deport out large-scale, risky commercial activities. The beginning mercantile companies were formed; among the most famous were the British East India Company in 1600 and the Dutch West India Visitor in 1602.

The wealth accumulated in this style was so used to strengthen the military appliance of the state, which in turn was a determining factor in the conquest of new territories and the exclamation of economical supremacy over rival nations.

When precious metals began to menstruum into or out of a country in proportion to its sales or purchases of foreign goods, mercantilists suggested that sovereigns strengthen international trade, as the primal premise of mercantilism was to encourage exports and discourage imports. To achieve this goal mercantilists suggested that sovereigns utilize trade protectionism, a trade policy that states adopted to discourage imports (the purchase of goods from other states) through the imposition of heavy duties; the purpose was to prevent gold and precious metals from leaving the country.

International merchandise was considered a "null sum game": enriching 1 country could only be accomplished past impoverishing others.

Thus in a trade commutation one party became wealthier (the party that increased the gold entering the country due to sales) and the other became poorer (the one that decreased its gold supply considering it was spent to buy goods not produced within its territory). It took centuries before this idea of market place substitution disappeared (and it even so has not completely vanished).

Read full chapter

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/commodity/pii/B978012816027500001X

Classical theories of consumption

Bingxin Wu , in Consumption and Management, 2011

The consumption thoughts of William Piffling

English language classical political economics is considered to exist the beginning of Western economics. Classical political economics reflects the age and class characteristics of capitalism during its inception and development period; it emphasizes capital accumulation and advocates consumption frugality. It affirms the condition and office of consumption compared with mercantilism.

The core of Niggling's consumption thought insists on less consumption and more aggregating. He thinks that abundance of products for consumption leads to over-consumption, and over-consumption can make people become lazier. Workers are satisfied with a minimum living standard, and so he thinks that law should only ensure that the workers tin get the most necessary life materials. If the life materials extended to the workers are doubled, so, what the workers do will be halved compared with what they are capable of completing when their wages are not doubled. For order, that is tantamount to losing the products created by the same amount of labor. He besides classifies capital expenditure according to the caste to which the expenditure is favorable to production; they are eating and drinking, purchasing clothing and furniture, building houses, improving land, mining and fishing as well every bit the enterprise of importing gold and argent from abroad in turns. It indicates that his idea is too heavily marked by mercantilism. He insists on using revenue enhancement to modify the proportional relation between consumption and accumulation: 'Through imposing taxation on people who indulge in eating and drinking, the fund accumulated can be used for useful practice, such as improving land, fishing, mining and opening factories. It is obvious that this kind of taxation is benign for the country where these people are located' (Petty, 1662).

Read full chapter

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B9781907568077500031

Liberalism and War

R. Latham , in International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2001

3.3 The Development of International Trade

In much liberal thinking, the rise of commercial classes was to be complemented in the international realm past the emergence of a robust system of international free merchandise for them to participate in. An overriding concern of liberals in this area has been to counteract mercantilist tendencies in the foreign policies and relations of states. Mercantilism was associated with the pursuit past autocratic states of sectional economical admission to trade routes and special concessions for the extraction of resources—the economic benefits of admission for one state would be airtight off to other states. Liberals feared that gaining access or enforcing exclusivity constituted grounds for state of war.

Even as mercantile practices became less prominent in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries as compared with the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, liberals still worried that protectionist policies could reinforce the sense of rivalry between states. Indeed, colonialism, which had reached new heights in European policy at the stop of the nineteenth century, was mostly understood by liberals to be a mercantilist phenomenon that fed competition (looting brings a set of people and places into the orbit of one state and not another). Liberals generally believed that states were willing to get to state of war over colonies to protect their interests.

The effectiveness of international trade equally an antitoxin to these practices in the international realm rests on the prospect that, instead of seeking colonies or exclusive access, states would merely promote merchandise between their citizens and the rest of the earth. A vested country involvement in securing open access to resource, peoples, and places would develop and concerns with facilitating marketplace contest between individual economic actors would shape policies. The connections betwixt individuals beyond national boundaries would deepen and widen and rivalry would take form in the productive field of the market rather than the interstate system. This ultimately would reinforce, every bit John Stuart Mill (Silberner 1946) believed, an involvement in peace rather than war (an action that could be highly disruptive in the international economic system).

Read full chapter

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/scientific discipline/article/pii/B008043076704506X

Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, Volume 2

W. Edward Steinmueller , in Handbook of the Economic science of Innovation, 2010

3.one.four Protectionist measures

In recent times, protectionist measures aimed at bolstering baby industries or providing an incentive for import substitution have generally been proscribed through international merchandise agreements. While it is mostly accepted that countries would seek to support and promote domestic industries, doing so past shielding them from domestic contest from imports or financing their competitive struggles with strange firms was prohibited as being inconsistent with the general principle of gratis trade. Even if some merit might exist for supporting infant industries, every bit many countries have washed historically, implementing this support through protectionist measures would complicate trade governance past blurring the boundary between mercantilism and efforts at industrial promotion.

Credence of this argument is by no means universal. In the context of this chapter, the pivot of the controversy is the assumption that the prohibited actions are either ineffective or redundant to other policies that would be similarly constructive. This assumption is supported to the extent that noesis is a global public good or that the available processes of knowledge generation and distribution, that is, ones that do not contravene agreements (such every bit thematic funding), volition suffice to permit entry into new areas of production or commercial activity. The supposition is contradicted if these conditions do not concord. While it is straightforward to find examples of countries entering new industries, contradicting a strong version of the babe industry argument, it is possible, although nigh impossible to establish, that prohibitions of protectionist measures have prevented entry into "important" industries (a broad counterfactual) or created "weak" entrants (for which there may exist many other reasons).

The same problems apply to the analysis for historical examples where it is claimed that protectionist measures were of critical importance in supporting domestic applied science evolution. While the fact of such measures is undisputed, the counterfactual claim of what would take happened in their absence is largely speculative. For case, in the case of the United States, domestic pig iron-making chapters was aided by protectionist measures in the nineteenth century with greater event prior to the Ceremonious War than following—however, in neither menses is it likely that the industry would have disappeared without the tariff (Davis and Irwin, 2009; Irwin, 2000). The counterfactual (without protectionist measures) international division of labor in steel making in the latter half of the nineteenth century, during the most active period of American industrialization, is thus a thing of pure speculation.

Read full affiliate

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0169721810020125

Colonialism and Imperialism

Dierk Walter , in Encyclopedia of Violence, Peace, & Conflict (Second Edition), 2008

Economy

The economy of imperialism was characterized by various structures, but overall it was a trading system.

Merchandise

From the outset voyages to India in search of spices, merchandise was the aim and the means of expansion. Fifty-fifty where expansion began with conquest, destruction, and pillage, trading systems eventually evolved nether the protection of the new colonial governments.

The classical pattern of colonial trade was the substitution of colonial produce, either natural resources or agronomical produce, for manufacturing commodities from the mother state. A key feature was the global trade network, which connected the specific trading potential of several continents. Thus, for instance, the Atlantic triangular trade (sixteenth to nineteenth century) typically exchanged inexpensive manufactured appurtenances and firearms from Europe for slaves in West Africa, brought them to the American plantation colonies, where the profit from their auction would buy colonial goods for the journey dwelling or would be transferred to Europe in bills of exchange.

Where fifty-fifty an imperial merchandise network could not provide for adequate substitution commodities, bullion gained overwhelming importance. The economy of Espana as well every bit the majority of European trade in Asia until well into the nineteenth century was based on large shipments of Peruvian silver, benefiting from the fact that silver was comparatively cheaper in America than in Asia. Until the nineteenth century, merchandise with Asia was also the well-nigh important exception to the classical blueprint: Europe imported non only raw materials but also manufactured goods (dyed textiles, porcelain) from there.

Through systems of trade regulations, governments attempted to maximize the share of their subjects in world merchandise, thus supporting both the home economic system and the treasury (tariffs, taxation). Until the nineteenth century, the theory of mercantilism dominated these attempts. Typically, a mercantilist merchandise organisation confined colonial trade to shipping raw materials and cash crops to the mother state, and receiving in turn manufactured appurtenances. Many commodities (the classical 'colonial' produce such as carbohydrate, tobacco, coffee, dyestuffs) were likewise re-exported. Colonial manufacturing was restricted to domestic needs. Only the differences betwixt the powers were corking: Whereas British mercantilism was comparatively liberal and marked past exceptions, Kingdom of spain and Portugal surrounded their colonial empires with nearly impregnable walls of regulations.

The 2nd half of the nineteenth century witnessed the introduction by Great Great britain of free trade principles into the world economy. Britain's superior industries needed vast, open up markets worldwide rather than protection. Other colonial empires followed only reluctantly. By the terminate of the century, new protective tariffs began to regulate trade with their respective colonies in favor of the colonial powers. Notwithstanding, only in the case of Great United kingdom of great britain and northern ireland was the share of trade with its own colonies of whatsoever significance. Even here the bulk went to the Dominions (meet Table 2 ).

Table two. Share of own dependencies in consign trade of colonial powers

ca. 1870 (%) ca. 1900 (%) ca. 1930 (%)
France x 12.7
Frg <ane
Netherlands (EastIndia just) 40.6 16.8
UK: whole empire 26.8 34.1 37.ii
UK: dominions only 12.0 16.seven 20.6
U.s. v

Agronomics

Except when the indigenous population already produced consign commodities (every bit in some African regions), colonies with favorable natural conditions were adapted for the world market through the establishment of plantations or farming. The various forms of colonial agronomics, from sheep or cattle breeding (Australasia, South Africa, S America) to European-style farming (N America), to saccharide, tobacco, oil, prophylactic, java, or tea plantations (tropical climates in America, Africa, and Asia), all had an immense demand for cultivable land in mutual. But whereas plantations were capital- and labor-intensive, farming was non. And while the farms produced at least partially for domestic consumption, plantations merely provided cash crops for the world market place.

Industry

Although few manufacturing branches (armaments, textiles) had produced at least partially for the colonial consign trade since the seventeenth century, industrial production equally a whole only began to play a office in purple expansion in the early nineteenth century, and even and so information technology was not a major driving force. Undeveloped world regions were not a profitable market, and the majority of the industrial output of the colonial powers went to other industrial countries. The development of colonial industries did not really begin before World War Two.

Finance

Investments on the periphery were more important. From the early Caribbean plantations to the nifty infrastructural projects of the twentieth century (railroads, channels, roads), investment in the colonies was a risky, but, if successful, highly assisting business. Still, investment was not necessarily confined to the colonies of the respective land (come across Table iii ). But where investments of its subjects were, or appeared to be, threatened, an royal power had a very adept reason for intervention.

Table 3. Share of ain dependencies in strange investment of colonial powers 1913–fourteen

France viii.eight%
Germany 2.1%
UK: whole empire 47.3%
Great britain: dominions only 34.6%

Service sector

Shipping, banking, and insurance were key branches of the global trade network. They benefited from its existence, but even more from its expansion. This did not necessarily involve advocating formal rule, but the service sector could not lose where it was established.

Taxation

The state also profited from the colonial economy through taxation of its subjects in the colonies. Some possessions with large indigenous populations offset seemed to exist goldmines for the state that had the opportunity to siphon off the profits of the colonial economic system and revenue enhancement the inhabitants. Somewhen, most colonies turned out to exist very costly in terms of running and defending them, and so that the home government, in dissimilarity to businessmen, benefited piffling or non at all.

Read full chapter

URL:

https://world wide web.sciencedirect.com/scientific discipline/commodity/pii/B9780123739858000301

The Pacific alliance during détente (1969–78)

Matteo Dian , in The Evolution of the US–Nihon Brotherhood, 2014

Armed forces self-sufficiency as a reaction to abandonment

We have analysed the consequences brought most by the changed international surround and the upshot the new U.s. strategy in East Asia had on political settlement of the alliance. The adjacent step will be to assess the impact these variables had on armed services preparedness; namely, long-term burden sharing and the degree of military and technological interdependence.

In 1969, Us analysts assessed the SDF every bit incapable of repelling a major invasion past Soviet or Chinese forces without substantial assistance. The strongest branch of the Japanese armed services was the navy, which the DNSA defined as 'strongest non communist maritime strength in Asia, fully operational and in fantabulous combat readiness' (DNSA, 1969f). The military value of the MSDF, still, was partly undermined by being exclusively defensive.

Assessments on the Air Self-Defense Force were similar. Despite existence 'the almost advanced air force in non-communist Asia', Nippon'south air capabilities were damaged by the absence of offensive systems, such as long-range bombers, and past the shortage of jet fighters. Altogether, Japan's forces were considered unable to carry out the duties assigned them by the Nixon Doctrine. Subsequently 1969 Japanese armed services planning and the size of Japanese forces were fundamentally influenced by the changing international surround and by American retrenchment from mainland Asia.

Every bit far as military preparedness is concerned, the immediate reaction to the Nixon Doctrine was the pursuit of kokusanka (autonomy, self-sufficiency). This was a central characteristic of the political and strategic debate during the 1950s and the 1960s (Pyle, 1969; Samuels, 1991). Even so, at that fourth dimension the indigenisation of defence product was oriented towards technological autonomy rather than military self-sufficiency. Until the late 1960s, autonomous defence was subordinated to economic advancement and technological improvidence between military and non-military sectors (Samuels, 1994).

The conceptualisation of autonomy that marked the Japanese political soapbox upward to the 1960s was 'techno-national'. Put simply, information technology was aimed at establishing a coherent strategy of catch-upward industrialism that would assure economic prosperity and self-sufficiency, rather than but military self-reliance. 4 In the postwar period, this strategy was based on ii main phases: beginning, acquiring and indigenising foreign military design development and manufacturing capabilities; second, diffusing these capabilities every bit widely as possible throughout the economic system. The new course taken by the US undermined the strategic underpinnings of this arroyo. Therefore, since 1970 the concept of autonomy assumed a decisively armed forces connotation (Friedman and Samuels, 1993). Proponents of armed services self-reliance foresaw a Japanese armed forces independent of the United states of america and technologically completely autonomous. This conceptualisation of kokusanka implied that Nippon needed to acquire independent national–industrial and armed services strength.

In 1969 the JDA proposed comprehensive reform of force structures. It was aimed at increasing the quality of the JSDF, enhancing autonomous defence production and defense force exports. The proposed size of the SDF was shut to 1 one thousand thousand. In 1970, the JDA noted, in its Bones Policy on Equipment and Development, that 'Democratic defense force production is crucial to autonomy for autonomous defence and more than mostly for autonomy in foreign policy.' Moreover, it added, 'it is desirable for Japan to be dedicated with equipment developed and produced by Japan alone. From this point on, the evolution and production of whatsoever military equipment volition exist express to Japanese industries as a affair of principle' (Green, 1995, p. 55). As the Japan Business Federation (Keidanren) confirmed in a policy statement in 1972, 'At that place is a worry that if Japan has to rely completely on another state'southward skilful intentions or power, our ability for independent military machine strength is neither possible nor appropriate, then we have to choose the brotherhood every bit our first policy. In that example, balancing and adjusting dependence on the Us with the maintenance of Japanese autonomy volition became a serious trouble' (Green, 1995, p. 55).

Such statements testify to how kokusanka inspired technological indigenisation and diffusion just had been reversed. After the Nixon Doctrine, the concept of autonomy was increasingly intended to increase room for manoeuvre in the alliance and more generally on the international scene, deviating from the techno-national project enshrined in the Yoshida Doctrine.

During early on 1971, US intelligence registered the effect the Nixon Doctrine was having on Japanese military planning. Information technology was argued that 'contempo adjustment in the US military posture and the enunciation of the Nixon Doctrine, take shaken Japanese self-approbation and led to considerable questioning of US intentions' (DNSA, 1971c). Moreover, it was estimated that the ongoing Third Defense Build-up Plan had increased the armed forces budget by 80 per cent compared with the second plan and by 500 per cent compared with the get-go.

The Fourth Build-Up Plan (which established defence procurement from 1972 to 1976) assumed indigenisation to be the centrepiece of JDA procurement policy. The new bones plan stressed that 'a nation's ability to equip itself for cocky-defence centres on industrial capacity. The SDF will consider the nation's industrial chapters and promote the domestic development and product of equipment' (DNSA, 1973). The plan also independent recommendations for military planners tasked with undertaking arms exports to do so 'with care'. In quantitative terms the plan proposed spending on the military and associated R&D to be increased by 350 per cent and a general increase in armed forces expenses of 220 per cent over iv years. The bear on of the Quaternary Build-Up Plan was reduced by the second Nixon Shock and devaluation of the dollar, making foreign purchases more attractive. Moreover, the same Nixon assistants helped alleviate the impact of the 4th Defence Build-upwards Plan past pressurising the Japanese to buy American equipment, specially submarines and aircraft, in lodge to rectify bilateral trade imbalance. Every bit Green (1995, p. 61) highlights, 'Without understanding for consequences, the Nixon Administration had upset the momentum of the kokusanka, which had been intentionally created ii years before with the Guam doctrine.'

However devaluation of the dollar, by the eye of the 1970s Nihon's military machine power, in terms of the number of men under arms, weapon systems, operational range and industrial back up capability, had emerged equally a very important gene in the balance of ability in Eastward Asia and the Western Pacific. Even though annual expenditure remained under the one per cent ceiling for the entire decade, the annual rate of increment in military expenditure was one of the highest in the world (between 8 and 10 per cent per twelvemonth) (Welfield, 1988, p. 103) (Figure iii.six). The touch of the second Nixon Shock, together with force per unit area from the United states of america and domestically based criticism, did not significantly reduce expansion of the SDF; but, it did frustrate the programme of Nakasone and the so-called 'revisionist faction' of the LDP 5 of reaching self-reliance in defence force product. At the terminate of the quaternary plan, the level of domestic production did non significantly exceed the level of 1971 when the tertiary plan expired.

Figure 3.6. Japan armed services expenditure

Source: Vocalist (1987)

The Miki authorities delivered the final blow to kokusanka past extending the 3 Principles of Export Bans to all nations and by banning the export of all armed services equipment. 6 The attempt to pursue technological autonomy in defence production was fundamentally inhibited by the ban on arms exportation. The exportation ban de facto stopped the Japanese arms manufacture from reaching the necessary calibration to be cocky-reliant and economically sustainable (Hughes, 2004).

Read total chapter

URL:

https://world wide web.sciencedirect.com/science/commodity/pii/B978184334766850003X

Civil Society, Concept and History of

H. Islamoglu , in International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2001

ii Koinonia Politike Transformed

In the sixteenth and the seventeenth centuries, post-obit a menses of religiously-driven civil wars, the idea of a Christian koinonia politike was replaced by the concept of the overriding sovereignty of the secular ruler who subordinated religious claims and restored peace. This was the Hobbesian moment in which the modern state rose to define, limit, and enforce moral alternatives to God'southward order (Maier 1987 ). Competition among European monarchies, warfare, civil war, and peasant uprisings all contributed to centralization of political power. By the end of the seventeenth century, this was reflected in the establishment of the sovereign monarch as a site of bureaucratic administration and regulation. Commercial expansion in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries meant that economic activeness became a main target of state regulation. The administrative, regulatory land was represented in discourses on economical administration that combined cameralism, mercantilism, political arithmetic, and bullionism.

Thus political or ceremonious society was no longer the politically constituted community characterized by a diffusion of political ability. Instead, political gild referred to the sphere of absolute sovereignty. Social harmony, which remained the legitimizing objective of dominion, was the product of bureaucratic regulations and no longer the outcome of reciprocal exchanges or negotiated settlements between the ruler and the different sectors of society.

Attempts to formalize the sovereign country also had the effect of pointing to the beingness of a sphere outside the political domain. In the latter role of the eighteenth century, a new conception of civil order as the site of self-regulation developed, referring to voluntary associations freed from the corporate grip of the Church and urban institutions and to the sphere of economic activity . This concept of a self-regulatory, cocky-governing society was ofttimes in opposition to the regulatory, political domain of the state.

The dichotomous conception of state and civil lodge, was, however, preceded by the distinction in Natural Law theory betwixt status civilis and condition naturalis (Tribe 1988). The latter was the sphere of discord which the English philosopher Thomas Hobbes (1588–1674) described equally bellum omnium contra omnes—barter gild in which individuals contracted with and against i some other (Hobbes 1949), and to which his countryman John Locke (1632–1704) assigned the contentious process of the germination of private property. For Hobbes, the state of nature ended when it submitted to the 'civil union' 'called state or civil society.' For the Prussian Cameralists of the same period, organization of economical activeness in political society, or its regulation, ensured the security and prosperity of the commonwealth, including providing the population with subsistence and productive employment. For the English mercantilist, James Steuart (1712–ninety), cocky-involvement had to be restrained and directed by the 'reason of land' if it were non to damage public good, which he defined in terms of England'due south increasing commercial success.

Concentration of political ability in administrative monarchies had resulted in a decline in the importance of the corporate bodies and deliberative institutions that had before served to mediate ability. Groups that were excluded from the political process, every bit well as new bureaucratic elites and commercial classes, sought inclusion through societal associations and political institutions that could provide them with a voice against absolutism. In France, Britain, and Deutschland respectively, Montesquieu (1689–1755), Ferguson (1723–1816), and Kant (1724–1804) proposed conceptions of ceremonious society focused on depiction of associational spaces, of environments for societal negotiations, of civility, and of publicity (Jacob 1991).

Responding to the despotism of the eighteenth-century French ancient authorities, Montesquieu saw in civil society (fifty'état civil) a context for the societal negotiation of the absolute power of the monarch that was not a domain separate from the monarchy. His concept of division of powers addressed a state of affairs in which the monarchy had severed itself from the network of power relations within the political society and had appropriated for itself a separate sphere of power (50'état politique). It sought to reintroduce the monarch into the l'état civil past ways of institutions that would check the accented authority of the ruler and residual it against the authority of the landed aristocracy, their advocates in the judiciary, and commercial interests (Richter 1998).

Kant showtime employed the notion of civil lodge, or bürgerliche Gesellschaft, in the sense of political society inseparable from the Prussian authoritarianism of Frederick the Great (1712–1786), which he considered indispensable for social stability. Secondly, bürgerliche Gesellschaft referred to the public sphere or a domain of literate citizenry that was split up from the loonshit of political ability and action. Kant regarded the political arena as the reserve of the state, or the ruler. Bürgerliche Gesellschaft referred to a sphere 'beyond the political social club,' 'beyond the particularistic concerns of political activity' where practical problems of governance could be debated on the basis of universal principles of reason. For Kant, the critical exercise of exposing actual state policies to the light of universal reason could act to restrain the absolute power of the ruler also every bit legitimizing his power (Ellis 2000). Kant'due south bürgerliche Gesellschaft was composed of individuals from the Prussian bureaucratic and bourgeois elites, educated and trained in state schools and administrative offices, every bit well as members of social clubs and associations, who could past dint of reason rise beyond the trappings of class or official condition.

The thinkers of the Scottish Enlightenment who addressed the issue of civil society did non limit themselves to the issue of restraints to centralized state authority. Adam Ferguson pointed to the corrosion of borough spirit in political order, where the successful commercial classes became servile to the administrative state, which provided them with a 'rule of constabulary' only deprived them of their traditional rights (Keane 1988, Ferguson 1995). He conceived of civil guild every bit networks of self-governing and cocky-regulating voluntary associations, such as self-assistance groups and 'friendly' or charitable societies, which had expanded rapidly in the eighteenth century and, in United kingdom of great britain and northern ireland, played an important function in poverty relief efforts. Ferguson pointed to the potential of voluntary associations for engendering civility beyond the special interests of land administration and the commercial classes. The central question facing Ferguson and other eighteenth century European thinkers was how society increasingly differentiated administratively and economically, could remain integrated and harmonious. For Ferguson, equally for his compatriot, David Hume (1711–1776), civility was the ground for social cohesion, and he saw it as rooted in sociability or moral and emotional communication among persons 'that fostered social bonds and friendships and cultivated manners and moral tastes' (Trentmann 2000). Ferguson did not place ceremonious lodge in opposition to the state; rather, civil order constituted a protective shield from the uncertainties of social and political life.

Read full affiliate

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B0080430767026784

Not just for profit: civil enterprises and values-based organizations

Leonardo Becchetti , ... Stefano Zamagni , in The Microeconomics of Wellbeing and Sustainability, 2020

10.9 The difficult innovations of a civil enterprise

Earlier concluding this chapter dedicated to companies that are more complex than those motivated purely past profit, there is more we tin say about the market, VBOs, and ceremonious entrepreneurs. We begin not from a economist from the past, only from 1 of the classical mainstream economists, David Ricardo. In 1817 this great British economist formulated one of the first real economic theories, which is still relevant today.

In previous theory, and in mercantilism in particular, trade and commutation happened when there were "absolute" advantages. If Britain and Portugal have the post-obit price structure, so specialization and international merchandise are advantageous ( Table 10.1) .

Table 10.1. Absolute advantages (numbers express costs).

Uk Portugal
Cotton wool products: v Cotton wool products: viii
Wine: 6 Wine: 5

Ricardo demonstrated that even in cases where there were simply "relative" advantages, merchandise is advantageous for both (Table 10.2):

Table 10.2. Relative advantages.

United kingdom Portugal
Cotton products: five Cotton wool products: viii
Wine: 6 Wine: 7

Ricardo showed us that even in a world in which U.k. is more than efficient than Portugal in both sectors, information technology can exist advantageous for Britain to specialize in the sector where is relatively the strongest (where it has a comparative advantage). The point is that even in this instance merchandise with the weakest benefits the strongest too. The archetype example is that of a lawyer who, although she can type faster on her reckoner than her secretary, even so has an reward in hiring a secretarial assistant and concentrating instead on her legal piece of work; this is the well-known concept today of "opportunity cost." Just as in the case of Great britain, in hiring a secretarial assistant who is not as fast as she is the lawyer is not offering help or charity, rather, she and the secretarial assistant both do good from the substitution. When the market includes the weakest and turns it into an opportunity for the common good, for the good of all and of each one, then it is playing its civilizing role.

Why is this theory pregnant for VBOs? Consider the important innovation of the emergence of social cooperation in Italy. Disadvantaged people who are included in companies often go opportunities for mutual benefit, fifty-fifty for the companies that hire them, rather than existence a "cost" or an act of clemency. (There is also public participation in the costs of hiring these people, which is nearly e'er socially efficient.) Disabled workers were essentially seen as a cost or a burden past companies and trade unions; social cooperation was truly innovative when ways were plant for these disadvantaged workers to become a resource for companies as well.

In such cases the persons who are "helped" feel that they are in a reciprocity-based human relationship, which is an expression of greater dignity. They exercise non feel they are being helped, but rather that they are agents in a contract that is mutually beneficial, and so they feel themselves more than costless and equal. Fifty-fifty a person affected by Downwards syndrome tin can participate in a mutually advantageous contract with a visitor, although it requires truly innovative abilities by civil entrepreneurs. Mutual advantage is always a possibility, merely it does not happen automatically or e'er; it requires creativity and much more, but when information technology happens the market becomes a true instrument of inclusion and authentic human and ceremonious growth. In fact, a benefactor's sacrifice is not always a practiced sign for those who receive the help, because it can limited a ability human relationship that may exist concealed by good faith.

Ceremonious entrepreneurs should give themselves no peace until the people included in their VBOs experience themselves to exist useful to the company and to lodge, rather than assisted by a philanthropist. Consider micro-credit. Bringing the excluded into the banking system was one of the principal economic innovations of our time. It liberated people – women in particular – from poverty and exclusion much more efficiently than many international help interventions. If an intervention does not aid all parties involved, it can inappreciably be of real assistance for someone. If I do not feel benefited less than I do good someone else, the other will rarely feel truly benefited by me, especially when the relationship endures over time. Variety is the constabulary of life, enabling relationships that do not deteriorate, simply rather grow in mutual dignity.

Read full chapter

URL:

https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B9780128160275000100